Are we in for a bumpy ride?
How bumpy? And for how long?
At the National People’s Congress
in Beijing in March 2015, China’s Premier Li Keqiang announced a growth target
of 7 percent, acknowledging that “deep-seated problems in the country’s economy
are becoming more obvious.”1 1.Koh Gui Qing and Kevin
Yao, “China signals ‘new normal’ with higher spending, lower growth target,”
Reuters, March 5, 2015, reuters.com. Three months later and thousands
of miles away in Washington, the World Bank lowered its growth forecasts across
the board and asked the US Federal Reserve Bank to delay any contemplated rate
hikes. The World Bank’s chief economist said that it had “just switched on the
seat belt sign. We are advising nations, especially emerging economies, to
fasten their seat belts.”2 2.Anna Yukhananov, “World
Bank sees slower global growth, urges Fed to wait on rates,” Reuters, June 10,
2015,reuters.com.
So it’s going to be a bumpy ride? How bumpy? And for how long?
Day-to-day developments in the
world economy have become increasingly complex and global in their
implications. Economic shocks, from Greece to China to Russia, are now of
greater concern because around the world, traditional policy tools have already
been used and financial resources depleted to help economies recover from the
last downturn. Strategic decisions have become correspondingly more
consequential. Shocks are inevitable, but strategists must find ways to extract
the signals from the noise to understand what’s over the horizon.
Three interlinked factors have
the potential to shift the global economy from one long-term outcome to
another: aggregate demand, structural challenges, and diverging growth
patterns. First, in the near term, the major economies continue to struggle to
achieve self-sustaining growth in aggregate demand. This continues despite
years of monetary and fiscal stimulus, as well as the recent drop in oil
prices. Second, the world’s major economies face long-term structural
challenges, including rising debt loads, aging populations, and inadequate or
aging infrastructure. Success or failure in resolving these structural
challenges will determine the speed of long-term growth in these economies.
Third, the world’s major economies have increasingly diverged in the last few
years. In the past, global integration has driven convergence. The prospects
for further integration have become less certain. The global financial shock
was followed by years of weak growth and concerns over rising inequality. The
path to renewed and stronger growth remains elusive.
Sidebar
The McKinsey Global Growth Model: Methodology
The analyses presented in this paper are based on
estimates produced by the McKinsey Global Growth Model. The model provides an
integrated framework for understanding how macroeconomic trends interact with
the processes that drive global growth.
The McKinsey model incorporates more than a dozen
major international databases from such institutions as the United Nations, the
World Bank, the International Monetary Fund, and the Bank for International
Settlements. Selection of data sources is based on their authoritativeness,
comparability, extended time series, and country and concept coverage. The
result is a historical database that provides complete time-series data for
more than 150 concepts and 110 countries over 30 years.
The structure of the model emphasizes the drivers
of economic growth, including demographic factors, education, energy supply,
physical capital, and some determinants of total factor productivity. It
captures the long-term effects of urbanization and industrialization, as well
as the impact of sociopolitical institutions, especially on finance and
governance. Because business-cycle fluctuations affect growth in the short
term, the model also links trade and international capital flows, credit and
asset markets, and the monetary relationships that determine inflation,
interest rates, and exchange rates.
Model estimates are generated
using a series of advanced econometric techniques. In particular, we use
dynamic error-correction-estimation techniques to address issues of
nonstationarity in the data. We use two-stage least-squares techniques to
mitigate potential simultaneity biases. In addition, because we aim to
characterize the drivers of growth over long time horizons, we pool the
information across a sample of countries with widely varying levels of
development. The result is a simulation tool that allows us to generate
plausible ranges for future growth for 20 core countries and nine regions.
Given the consequences of
these interlinked factors, it is small wonder that near-term developments have
taken on oversized importance. Our approach has been to work backward from a
series of long-term outcomes, determined by the degree to which the structural
challenges have been met and global growth has become more or less divergent.
We are then able to move forward, articulating the scenarios likely to emerge
in the path ahead from near-term developments (see sidebar, “The McKinsey
Global Growth Model: Methodology”).
Near-term signals and
long-term forces
The world’s major economies,
emerging and mature alike, have been experiencing clearly divergent growth
paths in the first half of 2015, in some cases due to unexpected challenges
(Exhibit 1). The US economy contracted in the first quarter; growth returned to
the eurozone, even as a crisis loomed in Greece. Chinese policy makers
continued to steer cautiously between the risks of a slowdown and those of
rising debt levels. In India, growth accelerated in anticipation of reforms,
while lower oil prices and economic sanctions contributed to a contraction in
the Russian economy.
· Enlarge
These developments may signal
the return of country-level business cycles, suppressed in the depths of the
global economic downturn. Yet they may also be its lingering effects,
suggesting that deeper forces are at work.
We believe that three sets of
forces will shape the global economy over the coming decade. The first two are
stimulus policies and shifting energy markets. These are near-term forces,
whose effects are felt on a daily basis. The next two forces, urbanization and
aging, are powerful, inexorable trends aggravating ongoing structural
challenges. Finally, two forces are of uncertain and variable magnitude:
technological innovation and global connectivity. All of these trends could
intermittently disrupt and transform sectors.
Near-term factors
Stimulating aggregate demand. Of
immediate concern is the persistent problem of weak aggregate demand relative
to overall economic capacity. The International Monetary Fund estimates that
production in the ten largest advanced economies was 2 percent below potential
in 2014. This gap was smaller than it had been in 2009 (3.3 percent) but
significantly worse than the surplus of 0.8 percent that prevailed in the early
2000s.33.World Economic Outlook
Database, International Monetary Fund, April 2015, imf.org.
All major economies except China experienced significantly weaker demand in the
aftermath of the global financial crisis. Many governments and central banks
responded with fiscal and monetary stimulus programs that fostered the low
real-interest-rate environments which have endured for over five years. The
McKinsey Global Institute reviewed the recent performance of advanced economies
and found that they had all increased rather than reduced their overall debt
levels—in some cases, by more than 50 percent.4 4.For more, see “Debt and (not much) deleveraging,” McKinsey Global Institute,
February 2015.
Complicating the picture is
the question of whether real interest rates will remain low (Exhibit 2).
Persistently low interest rates encourage investors to search for yield and
safety, creating the preconditions for asset bubbles and further volatility in
international financial flows.
· Enlarge
Economists are concerned that unconventional
monetary policies have distorted rather than bolstered the demand picture. In
the United States, for example, the Federal Reserve signaled for months that it
would raise rates by the end of 2015, heralding a return to a more
conventional, interest rate–driven monetary policy. In the interim, however,
results were tepid and now a rate hike may be further delayed. The challenges
faced by the Federal Reserve in timing rate increases will be encountered in
the eurozone and Japan in due time. Demand in major markets remains weak
enough, furthermore, that a misstep in any one of them will be felt by the
others.
Energy-market transformations. Oil
prices fell by 50 percent in the latter half of 2014. Even after a slight rebound,
they remained well below average levels of the past five years. For energy
consumers, the lower energy prices have provided a welcome respite; for
producers, they challenge fiscal stability. The breakeven oil price—the price
at which a fiscal surplus turns into a deficit—is estimated at $57 for Kuwait
and $119 for Algeria.5 5.Regional economic outlook
update: Middle East and Central Asia, International Monetary Fund, May
2055, imf.org.
Countries have so far managed the crunch by drawing down reserves and through
exchange-rate movements, but these are short-term actions and direct fiscal
adjustment lies on the horizon. Elsewhere, the fall in oil prices is slowing
further investment in energy sectors, notably unconventional oil and gas.
Global energy intensity has
fallen over the past several decades, so oil-price shocks are felt differently
in different parts of the globe. The energy productivity of the ten largest
advanced economies today is 74 percent of what it was in 1980.6 6.Measured as dollars of
GDP per metric ton of oil equivalent. Beyond the advanced economies, however,
the picture changes. Thanks to the increasing size of the emerging economies,
world energy productivity was able to rise by 33 percent between 1980 and 2002
(remaining relatively flat thereafter).
In assessing the ultimate
impact of recent energy-market shifts, strategists are seeking to discover what
will happen not in the next year but in the next decade. Only on two other
occasions during the past 30 years, in 1985 and 2008, did the oil price fall as
steeply as it did in 2014. The recoveries from these two events were very
different affairs and are instructive for today. In 1985, excess production
capacity led to stable prices for nearly a decade after the initial price
decline. The 2008 decline in prices was part of the financial crisis; prices
dropped precipitously and then quickly rebounded as demand recovered,
especially in emerging markets (Exhibit 3).
· Enlarge
Persistent demand weakness and
falling oil prices are the stuff of daily headlines, but associated effects
could drive alternative economic outcomes for the next decade. The complication
is that deeper forces are at work.
Inexorable factors
Unlike the variegated impact
of demand stimuli and energy-market shifts, the effects of urbanization and
aging are predictable and are tilting the global economy in one general
direction: toward emerging markets. Increasing urban congestion and an aging
labor force impose burdens—among them, lower productivity, falling demand, and
rising health and pension loads—on all economies. The challenges are clear. The
uncertainty lies in how economies will adapt to them.
Rapid urbanization. From
Brazil to China, emerging economies are urbanizing with unprecedented rapidity.
Rural populations are responding to rising industrial opportunities and
burgeoning growth, and the economic weight of cities in the world economy
continues to rise. McKinsey research indicates that 46 of the world’s 200
largest cities will be in China by 2025, a sign too of the eastward migration
of the global economy’s center of gravity.7 7.McKinsey’s CityScope
Database; see also Richard Dobbs, James Manyika, and Jonathan Woetzel,No
Ordinary Disruption: The Four Global Forces Breaking All the Trends, New
York, NY: PublicAffairs, May 2015, page 21. In recognition of the urbanization
challenge China faces, the Chinese government is moving with astonishing speed
to meet its climate goals, because the pollution produced by outmoded power
generation and manufacturing is starting to interfere with the quality of life
in urban areas. India is facing similar and intensifying urban challenges but
has not yet moved with China’s determination.
Demographic pressures. The
labor force, on which economic activity depends, is both aging and shrinking.
It is expected to contract by 11 percent in China by 2050, even as the
country’s economy expands. The shrinkage in continental Europe is expected to
be even more dramatic. As life spans are growing and birthrates falling,
furthermore, an aging working population in advanced and emerging economies
will be supporting ever-higher numbers of retirees. Among the major economies,
only the United States has a demographic profile favorable to long-term
economic growth. For the rest of the leading economies, expected productivity
improvements will not bridge the gap. Without a fundamental economic and
cultural shift, favoring continued participation of older workers and the
introduction of more women workers and immigrant labor, many economies would
face serious growth constraints within ten years (Exhibit 4).
· Enlarge
Uncertain factors
The direction and potential
impact of the final factors in our review are less certain than the effects of
urbanization and aging. In one sense, technological innovation and global
connectivity are already familiar phenomena. As the science-fiction author
William Gibson remarked 15 years ago, “The future is already here—it’s just not
very evenly distributed yet.”8 8.“The science in science
fiction,” Talk of the Nation, NPR, November 30, 1999, npr.org.
Technological disruption has become a pervasive feature of the modern global
economy, but its extent is uncertain. Especially important is the question of
how much innovation will come from China, India, and other emerging economies.
The opening of markets has accelerated the growth of global supply chains and
productivity, but will this growth continue?
Technological innovation. Technological
innovation has reached a level in the major economies where significant
structural changes are in process or have already occurred. Digitization has
transformed the telecommunications, media, financial-services, and retail
sectors. Consumers are using mobile devices to connect to an ever-widening
range of goods and services, while businesses embed such devices more deeply in
functional processes and industrial activity. High-tech innovations in robotics
and 3-D printing could enable mature and emerging economies alike to boost
labor productivity and rapidly expand industrial horizons, while also shifting
global trade patterns.
The deep innovation and
structural shifts at the industry level have also given rise to concerns about
market power and privacy. The theft of credit-card numbers, industrial
espionage, and breaches in personal data all raise new questions about the
security of information. Major technology companies face rising antitrust
scrutiny. Assuredly, innovation will continue, but to what extent will it occur
more globally, and how rapidly will it spread across borders?
Global connectivity. The
constituents of the global economy in 2015 are more deeply interconnected than
ever before. Trading relationships are increasingly dense and complex, and they
have rebounded rapidly since the global downturn. Today, China is a peerless
world-trade hub and Latin American, Indian, and Middle Eastern trade has risen
in world-economic weight. Among other factors, the recapitalization of banks,
regulatory change, and monetary stimulus have exercised countervailing effects
on financial flows, which remain well below pre-crisis levels (Exhibit 5).
Concerns about the transmission and impact of financial shocks remain high on
the global regulatory agenda.
· Enlarge
More than 20 years have passed
since the conclusion of the last round of multilateral trade negotiations in
1994. More economies have been opened since then, and the scope of trade
agreements has widened. The focus in developed economies has shifted toward the
opening of investment opportunities and easing of restrictions on services; in
emerging markets, agricultural subsidies have been a priority. These areas have
proved especially intractable in a multilateral context, but regional and
bilateral trade agreements of widening scope have nonetheless proliferated
since 1994.
As the last two decades have
demonstrated, increasing international trade flows can reshape national growth
trajectories. A rising caution pervades public debate about deepening economic linkages
among countries, however. The principal concerns go beyond the potential impact
on growth, even within specific sectors. The reservations are more focused on
the wider question of whether nations can agree on global rules that are
appropriate and supportive for an evolving economy.
The four scenarios
Our scenarios for 2015 to 2025
have been shaped by the three tightly linked sets of factors outlined
above—near term, inexorable, and uncertain. The interaction of these factors
will govern a number of crucial outcomes. Is weak growth in advanced economies
going to undermine the will to open more politically sensitive markets and
sectors? To what extent will inadequate infrastructure or restrictive markets
stall growth in emerging countries? How will falling commodity prices
complicate efforts to diversify commodity-driven economies? The longer-term
factors discussed above—urbanization, aging, technological innovation, and
global connectivity—anchor our four scenarios. The near-term factors—monetary
stimulus and energy prices—inform the path to the longer-term outcomes. These
dynamics have been framed by the intersection of two axes (Exhibit 6).
· Enlarge
The vertical axis measures the acceleration or
deceleration of growth and thus how well (or poorly) economies have tackled
their long-term structural challenges. Successful economies drive up
productivity and overall growth. The horizontal axis measures the extent to
which global growth is convergent. This is determined by a combination of near-
and longer-term factors. Countries can converge toward higher (or lower) growth
rates, for example, according to how successful they have been in implementing
and then unwinding their monetary and fiscal stimulus. In the long term,
increasing convergence is also determined by the global evolution of economic
rules of the road, covering the extent of economic activity, including goods
and services, migration, investment, and intellectual-property rights.
A convergent world would not
be impervious to shocks, but it would be better able to absorb them. Higher
global systemic resilience means that individual economies can recover more
quickly. Divergent outcomes, on the other hand, result when the policies of
individual countries are at odds, creating internal systemic imbalances that
can magnify the effects of a shock in a particular country. Divergence can also
slow the movement of shocks across borders—a movement that, unfortunately, is
common in an internationally linked world.
A final consideration is the
historical pace of global growth, which provides context for the scenarios.
This indicator has been remarkably stable since the mid-1980s. The rolling
ten-year average real growth rates hovered between 3.4 and 2.7 percent (Exhibit
7). Exhibits 8 and 9 illustrate how the intersection of the growth and
divergence axes over the next decade defines the four scenarios. “Global
synchronicity” (scenario 1) describes a world where most major economies tackle
their structural challenges, and are able exit from aggregate demand stimulus
smoothly. “Rolling regional crises” (scenario 4) describes the opposite
outcome.
With structural challenges
remaining largely unaddressed, the world economy becomes more vulnerable to
regional crises and grows increasingly insular. Two other scenarios capture the
cases in which growth accelerates but the major economies diverge (scenario 2,
“Pockets of growth”), and where the major economies converge to lower growth
rates (scenario 3, “Global deceleration”). In Exhibit 8, the four scenarios are
illustrated, with a growth breakdown for major economies and for energy- and
commodity-driven sector growth. Exhibit 9 presents the scenarios at a glance; more
detailed descriptions of each scenario follow.
· Enlarge
· Enlarge
· Enlarge
Scenario 1. Global
synchronicity: Convergence and rapid growth
In this scenario, the global
economy experiences the most robust long-term growth it has seen in more than
three decades, reaching 3.7 percent per year through 2025. The United States,
the eurozone, and Japan are able to make the transition to more sustainable
growth while exiting from their monetary stimuli with minimal disruption.
Likewise, policy makers in China implement incremental changes and guide
economic growth smoothly and gradually downward to a sustainable level. India
emerges as the fastest-growing economy over this period as it rides a wave of
reform, investment, and robust demographics. By 2025, the global economy will
have grown to $90 trillion in constant 2015 dollars, from $62 trillion in 2015.
As global growth gathers
momentum, liquidity from unconventional monetary policies is gradually absorbed
or withdrawn in the United States, eurozone, and Japan. Proliferating trade
agreements lead to the lowering of barriers in critical service industries and
to revivals of cross-border activity and technology transfer. The rapid
diffusion of innovation, bolstered by broader global trade arrangements, boosts
the share of exports in GDP for the G-20 from 25 percent today to 29 percent by
2025, or roughly at the growth rate of the early 2000s.
Financial-sector reforms in
emerging economies foster more market-driven and robust capital markets. Global
interest rates return to the “old normal” levels of the pre-crisis years.
Energy and commodity prices are buoyed as productivity-induced supply gains
cannot keep pace with emerging-market demand. As might be expected in such an
environment, employment growth rebounds and most countries see unemployment
rates fall and participation rise. India, China, and commodity-driven economies
account for 80 percent of employment growth. Elsewhere, policy changes in
advanced economies encourage aging workers to stay in the workforce longer,
while making it easier for women and part-time workers to stay employed.
Scenario 2. Pockets of growth:
Divergence with rapid growth
In this second high-growth
scenario, the growth picture becomes more uneven, as countries tackle
structural challenges in fits and starts. Global growth reaches 3.2 percent a
year over the course of the decade, a relatively high historical level, and by
2025 the global economy reaches $88 trillion in 2015 dollars.
The United States, China, and
India achieve satisfactory and even sporadically robust growth, while the
eurozone and Japan struggle. The unevenness of the expansion makes agreements
harder to reach on international protections for investors, intellectual
property, and agricultural subsidies. As a result, trade growth starts to slow
and remains effectively flat relative to GDP at 25 percent.
Some countries find it
difficult to exit from unconventional monetary policies, which continue to
distort credit channels and capital flows. The search of investors for higher
or more stable yields quickens, adding to volatility. Oil prices gradually
revive on higher demand, and producers of other commodities encounter more
frequent supply constraints.
Scenario 3. Global
deceleration: Convergence with slower growth
This lower-growth scenario is
defined by global convergence to a slower path. Global growth manages to reach
2.9 percent over the course of the decade, slightly below average for the past
three decades. The expansion is especially reliant on positive outcomes in
emerging markets. By the end of the decade, the global economy reaches $86
trillion in 2015 dollars.
Structural challenges remain
largely unaddressed but are offset in the near term by partly successful
efforts to revive demand. China avoids the worst effects of a “hard landing,”
but confidence in the financial and fiscal system is shaken, further weighing
on growth. China still accounts for nearly 23 percent of global GDP by 2025,
however. In the advanced economies, fiscal and monetary buffers to address
structural reforms are exhausted.
Near-term demand revives
globally, creating an opportunity for Europe and the United States to make
progress on financial services, privacy, and M&A activity, which becomes a
benchmark for global emulation. Trade is a more important driver of growth in
this scenario than in the previous one. The lower growth curve is a constraint,
but trade still accounts for 27 percent of the global economy. Demand for
energy (including oil) revives, but the availability of additional supply keeps
prices from recovering more quickly.
Scenario 4. Rolling regional
crises: Divergence and low growth
This scenario is the negative
image of the global-synchronicity scenario. Growth stalls and the world economy
is $11.4 trillion smaller than it would be in that scenario. “Rolling regional
crises” describes a world where structural reforms broadly stall, and aggregate
demand, especially in advanced economies, does not return in a sustainable way.
Deleveraging remains a drag on household balance sheets, and corporate-debt
levels continue to rise.
Increasingly, countries rely
on conventional and unconventional forms of fiscal and monetary stimulus. Real
interest rates remain in negative territory, but the growth outlook fails to
encourage renewed investment growth. Incremental fixed investment in the G-20
countries totals little more than half the level in the global-synchronicity
scenario.
With not enough economic
incentive, companies fail to invest in R&D and technological innovation
remains confined to a few regions. The diffusion of technology also slows down
as economies increasingly turn inward. Implicit and explicit restrictions on
international M&A activity proliferate, as do regulations inhibiting the
expansion of trade and technology. As a result, the share of exports in GDP for
G-20 nations rises more slowly, from 31 percent today to 34 percent by 2025.
Similarly, employment growth slows and the G-20 nations add 60 million fewer
jobs than they would in the global-synchronicity scenario. In a repeat of the
1980s, global oil supplies remain abundant and energy prices stay flat in real
terms.
In this scenario, the world
economy remains much more vulnerable to economic shocks, particularly from
financial flows. Low interest rates, combined with expanded financial
liquidity, create the conditions for volatile flows seeking yields in response
to the slightest hint of a change in the growth outlook.
Our global economic scenarios
suggest that the major economies face significant structural challenges. To
revive growth, these countries must tackle the challenges while navigating
constant reverberations from an interconnected world economy. Urbanization and
aging are tilting growth toward emerging markets; other trends are complicating
the picture. For strategists, the course of trade and information flows is of
crucial importance, as the direction and forces behind the flows determine how
industries will be affected. Rising south-to-south trade in goods creates a
very different set of opportunities than does increased services-driven trade
or increased investment based on production location.
Volatility and shocks are an
ever-present feature of the world economy. To take an example: in 2013, the
Federal Reserve suggested that it might slow its bond purchases later that
year. Soon yields on US bonds rose dramatically and capital flows to emerging
markets reversed, as investors now sought higher and safer yields in the United
States (and other developed markets). The World Bank later estimated that the
loss in capital flows to emerging markets from this one event amounted to
hundreds of billions of dollars in GDP. In many parts of the world, the policy
tools and financial reserves needed to absorb such shocks have been expended in
dealing with previous events. Understanding susceptibility and resilience to
shocks, from a national and global perspective, will allow strategists to make
better decisions about market entry, new investment, or market exit.
We hope that companies will
find the scenarios laid out in this paper helpful in strategy planning. They
have been designed as baselines against which different corporate strategies
can be tested, to reveal how industry-specific dynamics may evolve in response
to macroeconomic shifts. We believe that most companies will find that regular
pressure testing of their strategies in response to both macroeconomic and
industry shifts helps sustain growth in the face of challenging conditions.
About the authors
Luis Enriquez is
a director in McKinsey’s Brussels office, Sven Smit is a
director in the Amsterdam office, andJonathan Ablett is an expert
in the North American Knowledge Center in Waltham, MA.
The authors wish to thank Alan FitzGerald, Ezra
Greenberg, and Neha Nangia for their contributions to this article. The authors
would also like to acknowledge the support of Jaroslaw Bronowicki, Richard
Bucci, Debadrita Dhara, Krzysztof Kwiatkowski, Vivien Singer, Alok Singh,
McKinsey alumnus Giacomo Meille, and all their colleagues in McKinsey’s Global
Economics Intelligence group and McKinsey Global Institute Economics Research.
September 2015 |
byLuis Enriquez, Sven Smit, and Jonathan Ablett
Mckinsey
0 comentários:
Postar um comentário